File: secCint.html

package info (click to toggle)
anarchism 11.7-1
  • links: PTS
  • area: main
  • in suites: etch, etch-m68k, lenny
  • size: 19,196 kB
  • ctags: 601
  • sloc: makefile: 38
file content (384 lines) | stat: -rw-r--r-- 23,015 bytes parent folder | download
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
100
101
102
103
104
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
115
116
117
118
119
120
121
122
123
124
125
126
127
128
129
130
131
132
133
134
135
136
137
138
139
140
141
142
143
144
145
146
147
148
149
150
151
152
153
154
155
156
157
158
159
160
161
162
163
164
165
166
167
168
169
170
171
172
173
174
175
176
177
178
179
180
181
182
183
184
185
186
187
188
189
190
191
192
193
194
195
196
197
198
199
200
201
202
203
204
205
206
207
208
209
210
211
212
213
214
215
216
217
218
219
220
221
222
223
224
225
226
227
228
229
230
231
232
233
234
235
236
237
238
239
240
241
242
243
244
245
246
247
248
249
250
251
252
253
254
255
256
257
258
259
260
261
262
263
264
265
266
267
268
269
270
271
272
273
274
275
276
277
278
279
280
281
282
283
284
285
286
287
288
289
290
291
292
293
294
295
296
297
298
299
300
301
302
303
304
305
306
307
308
309
310
311
312
313
314
315
316
317
318
319
320
321
322
323
324
325
326
327
328
329
330
331
332
333
334
335
336
337
338
339
340
341
342
343
344
345
346
347
348
349
350
351
352
353
354
355
356
357
358
359
360
361
362
363
364
365
366
367
368
369
370
371
372
373
374
375
376
377
378
379
380
381
382
383
384
<html>
<head>

<title>Section C - What are the myths of capitalist economics?
</title>

</head>
<body>

<h1>Section C - What are the myths of capitalist economics?</h1>

Within capitalism, economics plays an important ideological role. Economics
has been used to construct a theory from which exploitation and oppression 
are excluded, by definition. We will attempt here to explain why capitalism 
is deeply exploitative. Elsewhere, in <a href="secBcon.html">section B</a>, we have indicated why 
capitalism is oppressive and will not repeat ourselves here.
<p>
In many ways economics plays the role within capitalism that religion 
played in the Middle Ages, namely to provide justification for the dominant
social system and hierarchies. <i>"The priest keeps you docile and subjected,"</i>
argued Malatesta, <i>"telling you everything is God's will; the economist
say it's the law of nature."</i> They <i>"end up saying that no one is responsible
for poverty, so there's no point rebelling against it."</i> [<b>Fra Contadini</b>,
p. 21] Even worse, they usually argue that collective action by working
class people is counterproductive and, like the priest, urge us to tolerate 
current oppression and exploitation with promises of a better future (in 
heaven for the priest, for the economist it is an unspecified "long run"). 
It would be no generalisation to state that if you want to find someone 
to rationalise and justify an obvious injustice or form of oppression 
then you should turn to an economist (preferably a "free market" one). 
<p>
That is not the only similarity between the "science" of economics 
and religion. Like religion, its basis in science is usually lacking 
and its theories more based upon "leaps of faith" than empirical 
fact. Indeed, it is hard to find a "science" more unconcerned about 
empirical evidence or building realistic models than economics. Just 
looking at the assumptions made in "perfect competition" shows that 
(see <a href="secC1.html">section C.1</a> for details. This means that economics is immune to
such trivialities as evidence and fact, although that does not stop
economics being used to rationalise and justify certain of these 
facts (such as exploitation and inequality). A classic example is 
the various ways economists have sought to explain what anarchists
and other socialists have tended to call <b><i>"surplus value"</i></b> (i.e.
profits, interest and rent). Rather than seek to explain its origin
by an empirical study of the society it exists in (capitalism), 
economists have preferred to invent "just-so" stories, little 
a-historic parables about a past which never existed is used to
illustrate (and so defend) a present class system and its inequalities
and injustices. The lessons of a fairy tale about a society that has 
never existed are used as a guide for one which does and, by some 
strange co-incidence, they happen to justify the existing class 
system and its distribution of income. Hence the love of Robinson
Crusoe in economics.
<p>
Ironically, this favouring of theory (ideology would be a better
term) is selective as their exposure as fundamentally flawed does 
not stop them being repeated. As we discuss in 
<a href="secC2.html">section C.2</a>, the 
neoclassical theory of capital was proven to be incorrect by 
left-wing economists. This was admitted by their opponents: <i>"The 
question that confronts us is not whether the Cambridge Criticism 
is theoretically valid. It is. Rather the question is an empirical 
or econometric one: is there sufficient substitutability within 
the system to establish neo-classical results?"</i> Yet this did not 
stop this theory being taught to this day and the successful critique
forgotten. Nor has econometrics successfully refuted the analysis,
as capital specified in terms of money cannot reflect a theoretical
substance (neo-classical "capital") which could not exist in reality. 
However, that is unimportant for <i>"[u]ntil the econometricians have 
the answer for us, placing reliance upon neo-classical economic theory 
is a matter of faith,"</i> which, of course, he had [C. E. Ferguson, <b>The 
Neo-classical Theory of Production and Distribution</b>, p. 266 and p. 
xvii] 
<p>
Little wonder that Joan Robinson, one of the left-wing economists who 
helped expose the bankruptcy of the neo-capital theory of capital,
stated that economics was <i>"back where it was, a branch of theology."</i>
[<b>Collected Economic Papers</b>, Vol. 4, p. 127] It
remains there more than thirty years later:
<p><blockquote><i>
"Economics is not a science. Many economists -- particularly those who
believe that decisions on whether to get married can be reduced to an
equation -- see the world as a complex organism that can be understood
using the right differential calculus. Yet everything we know about
economics suggests that it is a branch and not a particularly advanced
one, of witchcraft."</i> [Larry Elliot and Dan Atkinson, <b>The Age of 
Insecurity</b>, p. 226]
<p></blockquote>
The weakness of economics is even acknowledged by some within the 
profession itself. According to Paul Ormerod, <i>"orthodox economics 
is in many ways an empty box. Its understanding of the world is 
similar to that of the physical sciences in the Middle Ages. A few 
insights have been obtained which stand the test of time, but they 
are very few indeed, and the whole basis of conventional economics 
is deeply flawed."</i> Moreover, he notes the <i>"overwhelming empirical 
evidence against the validity of its theories."</i> It is rare to see 
an economist be so honest. The majority of economists seem happy 
to go on with their theories, trying to squeeze life into the 
Procrustean bed of their models. And, like the priests of old, 
make it hard for non-academics to question their dogmas as 
<i>"economics is often intimidating. Its practitioners . . . have 
erected around the discipline a barrier of jargon and mathematics 
which makes the subject difficult to penetrate for the 
non-initiated."</i> [<b>The Death of Economics</b>, p. ix, p. 67 and p. ix]
<p>
So in this section of our FAQ, we will try to get to the heart of 
modern capitalism, cutting through the ideological myths that 
supporters of the system have created around it. This will be a 
difficult task, as the divergence of the reality of capitalism 
and the economics that is used to explain (justify, more correctly)
it is large. For example, the preferred model used in neo-classical
economics is that of "perfect competition" which is based on a 
multitude of small firms producing homogenous products in a market
which none of them are big enough to influence (i.e. have no market
power). This theory was developed in the late 19th century when the
real economy was marked by the rise of big business, a dominance
which continues to this day. Nor can it be said that even small
firms produce identical products -- product differentiation and
brand loyalty are key factors for any business. In other words, 
the model reflected (and still reflects) the exact opposite of 
reality. 
<p>
In spite of the theoretical models of economics having little or
no relation to reality, they are used to both explain and justify
the current system. As for the former, the truly staggering aspect
of economics for those who value the scientific method is the 
immunity of its doctrines to empirical refutation (and, in some
cases, theoretical refutation). The latter is the key to 
not only understanding why economics is in such a bad state but
also why it stays like that. While economists like to portray 
themselves as objective scientists, merely analysing the system, 
the development of their "science" has always been marked with 
apologetics, with rationalising the injustices of the existing 
system. This can be seen best in attempts by economists to show
that Chief Executive Officers (CEOs) of firms, capitalists and 
landlords all deserve their riches while workers should be 
grateful for what they get. As such, economics has never been
value free simply because what it says affects people and society.
This produces a market for economic ideology in which those 
economists who supply the demand will prosper. Thus we find many
<i>"fields of economics and economic policy where the responses of 
important economic professionals and the publicity given economic 
findings are correlated with the increased market demand for 
specific conclusions and a particular ideology."</i> [Edward S. 
Herman, <i>"The Selling of Market Economics,"</i> pp. 173-199, <b>New 
Ways of Knowing</b>, Marcus G. Raskin and Herbert J. Bernstein
(eds.), p.192]
<p>
Even if we assume the impossible, namely that economists and their
ideology can truly be objective in the face of market demand for 
their services, there is a root problem with capitalist economics.
This is that it the specific social relations and classes produced 
by capitalism have become embedded into the theory. Thus, as an 
example, the concepts of the marginal productivity of land and 
capital are assumed to universal in spite the fact that neither 
makes any sense outside an economy where one class of people owns 
the means of life while another sells their labour to them. Thus
in an artisan/peasant society or one based around co-operatives,
there would be no need for such concepts for in such societies, 
the distinction between wages and profits has no meaning and, as 
a result, there is no income to the owners of machinery and land
and no need to explain it in terms of the "marginal productivity" 
of either. Thus mainstream economics takes the class structure of
capitalism as a natural, eternal, fact and builds up from there.
Anarchists, like other socialists, stress the opposite, namely
that capitalism is a specific historical phase and, consequently,
there are no universal economic laws and if you change the system 
the laws of economics change. Unless you are a capitalist economist, 
of course, when the same laws apply no matter what.
<p>
In our discussion, it is important to remember that capitalist 
economics is <b>not</b> the same as the capitalist economy. The latter
exists quite independently of the former (and, ironically, usually
flourishes best when the policy makers ignore it). Dissident economist
Steve Keen provides a telling analogy between economics and meteorology.
Just as <i>"the climate would exist even if there were no intellectual
discipline of meteorology, the economy itself would exist whether or
not the intellectual pursuit of economics existed."</i> Both share <i>"a 
fundamental raison d'etre,"</i> namely <i>"that of attempting to understand
a complex system."</i> However, there are differences. Like weather 
forecasters, <i>"economists frequently get their forecasts of the 
economic future wrong. But in fact, though weather forecasts are
sometimes incorrect, overall meteorologists have an enviable record
of accurate prediction -- whereas the economic record is tragically
bad."</i> This means it is impossible to ignore economics (<i>"to treat
it and its practitioners as we these days treat astrologers"</i>) as it is
a social discipline and so what we <i>"believe about economics therefore
has an impact upon human society and the way we relate to one another."</i>
Despite <i>"the abysmal predictive record of their discipline,"</i> 
economists <i>"are forever recommending ways in which the institutional
environment should be altered to make the economy work better."</i> By
that they mean make the real economy more like their models, as 
<i>"the hypothetical pure market performs better than the mixed economy
in which we live."</i> [<b>Debunking Economics</b>, pp. 6-8] Whether this 
actually makes the world a better place is irrelevant (indeed, 
economics has been so developed as to make such questions irrelevant
as what happens on the market is, by definition, for the best).
<p>
Here we expose the apologetics for what they are, expose the 
ideological role of economics as a means to justify, indeed ignore, 
exploitation and oppression. In the process of our discussion we 
will often expose the ideological apologetics that capitalist 
economics create to defend the status quo and the system of 
oppression and exploitation it produces. We will also attempt to 
show the deep flaws in the internal inconsistencies of mainstream 
economics. In addition, we will show how important reality is when 
evaluating the claims of economics. 
<p>
That this needs to be done can be seen by comparing the promise 
of economics with its actual results when applied in reality. 
Mainstream economics argues that it is based on the idea of 
"utility" in consumption, i.e. the subjective pleasure of individuals. Thus production is, it 
is claimed, aimed at meeting the demands of consumers. Yet for 
a system supposedly based on maximising individual happiness 
("utility"), capitalism produces a hell of a lot of unhappy 
people. Some radical economists have tried to indicate this 
and have created an all-embracing measure of well-being called 
the Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW). Their 
conclusions, as summarised by Elliot and Atkinson, are 
significant:
<p><blockquote><i>
"In the 1950s and 1960s the ISEW rose in tandem with per capita 
GDP. It was a time not just of rising incomes, but of greater 
social equity, low crime, full employment and expanding welfare 
states. But from the mid-1970s onwards the two measures started 
to move apart. GDP per head continued its inexorable rise, but 
the ISEW started to decline as a result of lengthening dole 
queues, social exclusion, the explosion in crime, habitat loss,
environmental degradation and the growth of environment- and 
stress-related illness. By the start of the 1990s, the ISEW was 
almost back to the levels at which it started in the early 1950s."</i> 
[Larry Elliot and Dan Atkinson, <b>Op. Cit.</b>, p. 248] 
</blockquote><p>
So while capitalism continues to produce more and more goods and, 
presumably, maximises more and more individual utility, actual 
real people are being "irrational" and not realising they are, 
in fact, better off and happier. Ironically, when such unhappiness
is pointed out most defenders of capitalism dismiss people's 
expressed woe's as irrelevant. Apparently <b>some</b> subjective 
evaluations are considered more important than others!
<p>
Given that the mid-1970s marked the start of neo-liberalism, the 
promotion of the market and the reduction of government interference 
in the economy, this is surely significant. After all, the <i>"global 
economy of the early 21st century looks a lot more like the economic 
textbook ideal that did the world of the 1950s . . . All these 
changes have followed the advance of economists that the unfettered 
market is the best way to allocate resources, and that well-intentioned 
interventions which oppose market forces will actually do more harm 
than good."</i> As such, <i>"[w]ith the market so much more in control of 
the global economy now than fifty years ago, then if economists are 
right, the world <b>should be</b> a manifestly better place: it should 
be growing faster, with more stability, and income should go to those 
who deserve it."</i> However, <i>"[u]nfortunately, the world refuses to dance 
the expected tune. In particularly, the final ten years of the 20th 
century were marked, not by tranquil growth, but by crises."</i> [Steve 
Keen, <b>Op. Cit.</b>, p. 2] 
<p>
These problems and the general unhappiness with the way society is 
going is related to various factors, most of which are impossible to 
reflect in mainstream economic analysis. They flow from the fact that 
capitalism is a system marked by inequalities of wealth and power and 
so how it develops is based on them, not the subjective evaluations of
atomised individuals that economics starts with. This in itself is 
enough to suggest that capitalist economics is deeply flawed and 
presents a distinctly flawed picture of capitalism and how it 
actually works. 
<p>
Anarchists argue that this is unsurprising as economics, rather than
being a science is, in fact, little more than an ideology whose main
aim is to justify and rationalise the existing system. We agree with
libertarian Marxist Paul Mattick's summation that economics is <i>"actually
no more than a sophisticated apology for the social and economic 
<b>status quo</b>"</i> and hence the <i>"growing discrepancy between [its] theories
and reality."</i> [<b>Economics, Politics and the Age of Inflation</b>, p. vii]
Anarchists, unsurprisingly, see capitalism as a fundamentally exploitative
system rooted in inequalities of power and wealth dominated by hierarchical
structures (capitalist firms). In the sections that follow, the exploitative 
nature of capitalism is explained in greater detail. We would like to point 
out that for anarchists, exploitation is not more important than domination. 
Anarchists are opposed to both equally and consider them to be two sides 
of the same coin. You cannot have domination without exploitation nor 
exploitation without domination. As Emma Goldman pointed out, under 
capitalism:
<p><blockquote><i>
"wealth means power; the power to subdue, to crush, to exploit, the power
to enslave, to outrage, to degrade . . . Nor is this the only crime . . .
Still more fatal is the crime of turning the producer into a mere particle
of a machine, with less will and decision than his master of steel and
iron. Man is being robbed not merely of the products of his labour, but 
of the power of free initiative, of originality, and the interest in, 
or desire for, the things he is making."</i> [<b>Red Emma Speaks</b>, pp. 66-7]
</blockquote><p>
Needless to say, it would be impossible to discuss or refute <b>every</b> 
issue covered in a standard economics book or every school of economics. 
As economist Nicholas Kaldor notes, <i>"[e]ach year new fashions sweep
the 'politico-economic complex' only to disappear again with equal 
suddenness . . . These sudden bursts of fashion are a sure sign of
the 'pre-scientific' stage [economics is in], where any crazy idea 
can get a hearing simply because nothing is known with sufficient 
confidence to rule it out."</i> [<b>The Essential Kaldor</b>, p. 377] We will 
have to concentrate on key issues like the flaws in mainstream economics, 
why capitalism is exploitative, the existence and role of economic power, 
the business cycle, unemployment and inequality.
<p>
Nor do we wish to suggest that all forms of economics are useless or
equally bad. Our critique of capitalist economics does not suggest 
that no economist has contributed worthwhile and important work to 
social knowledge or our understanding of the economy. Far from it. 
As Bakunin put it, property <i>"is a god"</i> and has <i>"its metaphysics. It
is the science of the bourgeois economists. Like any metaphysics
it is a sort of twilight, a compromise between truth and falsehood,
with the latter benefiting from it. It seeks to give falsehood the
appearance of truth and leads truth to falsehood."</i> [<b>The Political
Philosophy of Bakunin</b>, p. 179] How far this is true varies form 
school to school, economist to economist. Some have a better 
understanding of certain aspects of capitalism than others. Some
are more prone to apologetics than others. Some are aware of the
problems of modern economics and <i>"some of the most committed 
economists have concluded that, if economics is to become less
of a religion and more of a science, then the foundations
of economics should be torn down and replaced"</i> (although, 
<i>"left to [their] own devices"</i>, economists <i>"would continue to
build an apparently grand edifice upon rotten foundations."</i>).
[Keen, <b>Op. Cit.</b>, p. 19]
<p>
As a rule of thumb, the more free market a particular economist 
or school of economics is, the more likely they will be prone to 
apologetics and unrealistic assumptions and models. Nor are we 
suggesting that if someone has made a positive contribution in 
one or more areas of economic analysis that their opinions on 
other subjects are correct or compatible with anarchist ideas. 
It is possible to present a correct analysis of capitalism or 
capitalist economics while, at the same time, being blind to 
the problems of Keynesian economics or the horrors of Stalinism.
As such, our quoting of certain critical economists does not 
imply agreement with their political opinions or policy 
suggestions.
<p>
Then there is the issue of what do we mean by the term "capitalist 
economics"? Basically, any form of economic theory which seeks to 
rationalise and defend capitalism. This can go from the extreme of 
free market capitalist economics (such as the so-called "Austrian" 
school and Monetarists) to those who advocate state intervention 
to keep capitalism going (Keynesian economists). We will not be 
discussing those economists who advocate state capitalism. As
a default, we will take "capitalist economics" to refer to the 
mainstream "neoclassical" school as this is the dominant form of
the ideology and many of its key features are accepted by the others.
This seems applicable, given that the current version of capitalism
being promoted is neo-liberalism where state intervention is minimised
and, when it does happen, directed towards benefiting the ruling 
elite.
<p>
Lastly, one of the constant refrains of economists is the notion that 
the public is ignorant of economics. The implicit assumption behind 
this bemoaning of ignorance by economists is that the world should 
be run either by economists or on their recommendations. In 
<a href="secC11.html">section C.11</a> 
we present a case study of a nation, Chile, unlucky enough to have that 
fate subjected upon it. Unsurprisingly, this rule by economists could 
only be imposed as a result of a military coup and subsequent 
dictatorship. As would be expected, given the biases of economics, 
the wealthy did very well, workers less so (to put it mildly), in 
this experiment. Equally unsurprising, the system was proclaimed 
an economic miracle -- before it promptly collapsed.
<p>
So this section of the FAQ is our modest contribution to making 
economists happier by making working class people less ignorant 
of their subject. As Joan Robinson put it:
<p><blockquote><i>
"In short, no economic theory gives us ready-made answers. Any theory
that we follow blindly will lead us astray. To make good use of an
economic theory, we must first sort out the relations of the 
propagandist and the scientific elements in it, then by checking 
with experience, see how far the scientific element appears convincing,
and finally recombine it with our own political views. The purpose of
studying economics is not to acquire a set of ready-made answers to
economic questions, but to learn how to avoid being deceived by 
economists."</i> [<b>Contributions to Modern Economics</b>, p. 75]
</blockquote>

</body>
</html>